In an earlier blog entry, I found myself
arguing with Lord Macaulay’s famous 1841 speech about the extension of
copyright and its impact on the free trade of ideas. Macaulay argued that:
‘Copyright is monopoly, and produces all the effects which the general voice of
mankind attributes to monopoly. .... The effect of monopoly generally is to
make articles scarce, to make them dear, and to make them bad’.
In contrast, I suggested that
music collection societies, which operate as natural monopolies in most
countries, produce the opposite effects. Through their blanket licences they
help to make music accessible and they sometimes make it cheap. In fact, in
their ability to facilitate the business-to-business trade in music, they
provide the context in which the public is able to receive a great deal of its
music for free. They also help us to access a variety of music, as most of
their licensing schemes provide standard rates. Thus it costs users no more to
play a Beyoncé record than it does for them to play one Bis.
In addition, I argued that it is
those artists who manage to gain individual control over their copyrights who
are most likely to commit the evil that Maccaulay describes. It has generally
been established and successful performers, such as Taylor Swift, Prince or
Thom Yorke, who have managed to escape blanket licensing, whether that is the
licensing of a record company or the licensing of a collection society. There
are, of course, many positives about the degree of control that they have been
able to gain over their careers. This control has nevertheless enabled them to
make their work scarce (it doesn’t appear on streaming services) and to
sometimes made it dear (as those forced to purchase 1989 on CD
will testify).
Collection societies have, in
general, been transparent and fairly even-handed. Their licensing schemes are
made public and they offer standard terms. There are some injustices,
nonetheless. PRS, for example, has had policies that divert income from popular
music towards classical repertoire. MCPS, meanwhile, operates licensing schemes
that become cheaper the higher up you go. Smaller record companies have to pay
licences on the basis of the number of records of manufactured, while larger
companies pay on the basis of the number of copies sold. The former have to pay
their bills upfront; the latter are invoiced at a later date. Larger companies
also pay lower commission rates and benefit from further economies of scale if
they use MCPS to licence throughout Europe.
These various concessions don’t
compare, however, to the secrecy and inconsistency that surrounds streaming
deals. While some artists are escaping monopolies in order not to
appear on streaming platforms, record companies and publishers are escaping
monopolies in order to deal directly with the same sites. As I have previously documented, record
companies maintain that streaming falls under the ‘making available’ right
and they believe it is analogous to the sale of sound recordings rather than
the broadcast of digital radio. As a consequence they have been able to escape
the monopolistic licensing that public performance would entail. They have
conducted their own deals with streaming companies and they have avoided the
50% royalty that PPL accords to performing artists.
In some ways, this isn’t a great
break with tradition. Record companies have always made most of their deals
directly. The same is not true of the publishing companies: the majority of
their mechanical and performance licensing has taken place via the monopolistic
rates and regulations of the collection societies. By making direct deals with
the streaming companies they are entering unchartered waters. And this is
precisely what attracts them: they want to escape those collective rules. It’s
a complicated business nonetheless. Although record companies have convinced
themselves that streaming is largely ‘mechanical’ in nature, the publishing
world regards it as being equally divided between the performing and mechanical
rights. However, while it is relatively easy for publishing companies to
withdraw from MCPS and to self-administer the mechanical right for streaming
purposes, they have no such jurisdiction over the performing right. Songwriters
assign this right to their collection societies, rather than to their
publishers. Consequently, in this area it is the collection societies who have
control.
In Europe, the publishers’
solution to this problem has been to form ‘Special Purpose Vehicles’ with the
collection societies. These SPVs entitle the publishers to deal directly with
streaming companies and secure terms that cover both the performing and
mechanical rights. Any terms reached must be agreed by the collection
societies, however. Once the royalties have been calculated the income will make
its way to artists either via their collection societies (the performing right
share, presumably) or directly from their publishers (if this aspect of the
mechanical right is escaping the collection societies it will mark another
another area of income that is less readily identifiable as recorded music).
The publishers argue that
licensing directly enables them to negotiate higher royalties for their
artists, as they escape the flat demands of the collection societies. They also
argue that this method is more efficient for the streaming companies, as these
deals can be completed more quickly and can expand beyond the home country
remit of the collection societies. Songwriters are less comfortable. According
to the Music Managers Forum many of them
would prefer for streaming income to fall under the remit of the collection
societies:
possibly
because they trust their CMO [collection society] more than their label or
publisher; or because payments via CMOs often circumvent contractual terms that
enable labels or publishers to retain income; or because they feel collective
licensing is fairer to all, because everyone earns the same per play fees,
rather than bigger artists or rights owners having a better deal.
Nevertheless, if they are signed with a major publisher, they will
find that they have no choice. Sony/ATV has entered into an SPV with PRS and
GEMA, Universal has one with SACEM, Warner/Chappel has SPVs with a number of
collection societies including PRS, while BMG has a joint venture with GEMA.
Meanwhile, Kobalt, who are probably the most innovative publishing company
operating today, have actually bought the collection society, AMRA, which they
employ to conduct their SPVs.
And what does this
mean for the consumer? In the first instance, it might make some music scarce.
Although these direct deals are of potential benefit to the streaming companies
because they can licence one publisher for multiple territories, the drawback
is that they have to do deals with each publisher individually. Some catalogues
may well be left out. These joint ventures might also make music dear. If
publishers are able to negotiate higher royalties for their songwriters, then
the consumer may well end up paying for them. This could be directly, via
subscription charges, or indirectly, via the advertising fees that result from
fremium services. In addition, some music might end up being dearer than
others, which in turn might make it scarce. The withdrawal from monopoly
tumbles on and on . . .
No comments:
Post a Comment