When
campaigners have wished to curtail the duration of copyright they have called upon
the public. This practice is as old as copyright law itself.
The Statute of Anne (1710) is titled ‘An Act
for the Encouragement of Learning, by Vesting the Copies of Printed Books in
the Authors or Purchasers of Such Copies, during the Times therein mentioned’.
The time being referred to is the term of copyright, which was set at a period
of 14 years and could be extended by a further 14 years if the author was still
living at the end of the initial period.
The Act also indicated how it would encourage
learning. Copyright would inspire writers. It would motivate ‘learned men to
compose and write useful books’ because they would now have some legal
assurance of getting paid. In addition, the restricted duration of copyright
would boost reading, as it would lead to cheaper books. Books in copyright
would be monopolistically owned: an author would have the ‘sole right’ to their
books, while any bookseller to whom they assigned that right would have ‘the
sole liberty of printing and reprinting such book’. Although monopolies drove
up prices, the public domain would bring them down. Expiry of the term of
copyright would give any bookseller the liberty to reprint the work; the
ensuing competition would result in lower costs.
The price of books had been a genuine
concern. Prior to the Statute of Anne, the old licensing laws had given members
of the Stationers’ Company monopoly rights to book titles. When they were due
for renewal in 1693, a group of peers protested about the law, stating that it
‘subjects all Learning and true Information to the arbitrary Will and Pleasure
of a mercenary, and perhaps ignorant, Licenser; destroys the Properties of
Authors in their Copies; and sets up many Monopolies’. The Statute of Anne
aimed to curb the practice of these mercenaries, not only via limited copyright
duration, but also via a clause that allowed any ‘person or persons’ to raise a
complaint to the Lord Archbishop of Canterbury about any book whose price they
deemed to be ‘too high and unreasonable’.
Copyright law therefore aims to achieve a
balance. It has raised monopolies in order to protect the interests of authors,
and it limits them in order to make their works affordable. This idea was
carried through from British law into the American Constitution, which talks of
promoting ‘the progress of
science and useful arts, by securing for limited times to authors and inventors
the exclusive right to their respective writings and discoveries’. It can also
be seen in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, which counters ‘everyone
has the right freely to participate in the cultural life of the community’ with
‘everyone has the right to the protection of the moral and material interests
resulting from any scientific, literary or artistic production of which they
are the author’. In 1841 Lord
Macaulay made what is perhaps the most famous case for this balance. In a
speech to the British Parliament he argued that:
Copyright is
monopoly, and produces all the effects which the general voice of mankind
attributes to monopoly. .... The effect of monopoly generally is to make
articles scarce, to make them dear, and to make them bad. ... It is good that
authors should be remunerated; and the least exceptionable way of remunerating
them is by a monopoly. Yet monopoly is an evil. For the sake of the good we
must submit to the evil; but the evil ought not to last a day longer than is
necessary for the purpose of securing the good.
Mark
Rose believes this statement is a ‘standard point of reference in discussions
of the history of copyright’. It should be noted, however, that Macaulay was
campaigning against an extension to copyright. It is therefore natural that the
people who refer to him most are those who wish to free copyright from the
extensive grip of monopolies. This includes Andrew Gowers, who quoted the
speech in his 2006 Review of Intellectual Property. This report rejected an extension to sound recording
copyright in Britain. Gowers argued that a
properly functioning copyright
system is one where ‘incentive to innovate is balanced against the ability of
follow-on innovators to access knowledge’.
I think Gowers was right. If copyright is
supposed to both inspire artists to create and enable audiences to access their
work, extending the duration of sound recording copyright from 50 to 70 years
would be of little account to either cause. I’m not sure that Macaulay was the
best person to turn to, however. There is a lacuna in copyright debates.
Campaigners against extension have made excellent analyses of
the figure of the author, looking at the ways that corporations have
hidden behind artists’ rights in order to achieve their own ends. In contrast,
the effects of copyright upon the public have received less attention. Although
campaigning centres upon the idea of ‘access to knowledge’, there is little
investigation of how access works in different artistic fields.
Macaulay was arguing against claims for
copyright extension that were being made in respect of books. Books work
differently to music. Monopolies do make them expensive. Despite the
textual expansion of the internet and a continuing tradition of book readings,
the most common way of accessing a book is to pay for it: the majority of the
trade takes place between businesses and consumers. As a result, a book that is
in copyright will almost always be more costly than one that is in the public
domain. In fact, in arguing that the public domain leads to cheaper prices, Gowers used the book trade as his example, even though this was in a section of the Review of Intellectual Property that was debating the merits of sound recording copyright extension.
It should be noted, however, that there is a lot of ‘free’ music that is within copyright.
Or, to put it another way, the public enjoys a lot of music without having to
make a direct monetary exchange. We get to hear music for nothing on the radio;
on television; in the cinema; in shopping malls; in bars, pubs and clubs; and
on much of the internet, whether we are pirating or not. Many monetary
transactions relating to music take place business-to-business, rather than
business-to-consumer. According to PRS for Music figures from 2011 these
business transactions make up nearly a third of the market for music in the UK.
The value of B2B income for the music industries in that year was £1,057m,
while B2C income was £2,736m (split £1,112m for recorded music and £1,624m for
live music).
We do, of course, end up paying for much of
this B2B music in other ways. If music is being played for free by a public
broadcaster, its costs form part of the licensing fee. If it is free because it
is advertising-funded, we bear the cost of that advertising in the goods we are
encouraged to buy. Similarly, if music is being played for free in public
premises, we pay for it indirectly via other goods that the retailers are
selling us. There is also a human cost. We are denied agency: businesses choose
our music for us, and they choose songs that best underpin their own needs.
Moreover, we need to be aware that on many occasions when we hear music without
paying for it, it is us who are being sold to advertisers.
Music’s monetary waters are muddied further
when we begin to think about monopolies. There are situations when monopolies
actually help to keep costs down. Most of the music that we hear over airwaves and through public address systems is paid for via blanket
licences. The users of music don’t licence it directly from publishers and
record companies, they instead use collection societies. In most countries
there is just one collection society for each of the principal streams of
income. There will be a society that collects public performance income on
behalf of songwriters and publishers; a society that collects public
performance income on behalf of record companies and recording artists; and a
society that collects ‘mechanical’ income - money from record sales and other uses of recordings - on behalf of
songwriters and publishers (the record companies act for themselves when it
comes to collecting their own mechanical income and the royalties from
recording sales that are due to their artists). In Britain these societies are
PRS for Music, PPL and MCPS, respectively. They operate as monopolies.
One effect of blanket licensing is that all
music costs the same. The BBC pays as much to play a track by the Beatles as it
does to play a track by Bogshed (this is one of the reasons why it tends to use
such well known music in its own promotional films). Some of the collection
societies are more monopolistic than others, however. The writer members of PRS
assign the performing right in their works to the society. PRS therefore ‘owns’
this right and can offer its whole repertoire of works to the broadcasters and
premises it has licensing deals with. In contrast, MCPS merely administers the
mechanical right. Its relationship with songwriters is instead enshrined in its Membership Agreement, which covers a number of standard and blanket licences.
While PRS controls all aspects of the performing right on behalf of its
members, there are some areas where MCPS members can opt out of blanket
licences and instead negotiate directly with users. This includes music for
films, adverts and some commercial TV broadcasters. One reason why members
choose to operate in these areas is because they can negotiate higher fees. Here
monopoly breaks down and the Beatles will cost more than Bogshed. PPL’s monopoly
is also limited. It collects money from public premises and from broadcasters
but generates little online income. The majority of this licensing is instead
carried out directly by the owners of the sound recordings. PPL argue that this
‘reflects the prevailing view of
record companies that downloading and on-demand streaming is analogous to the
distribution of sound recordings, a traditional record company function’.
Moreover, if you want to use a
sound recording in an advert or a film you will have to negotiate directly with
its owners. If you want to use a major star or a big hit this will cost you
dearly.
As the income from recorded music declines,
the money that can be made from licensing becomes more important. Consequently,
some performers are seeking greater control of their rights. Artists such as
Prince have successfully gained ownership of their sound recording copyrights.
While most record companies use PPL to licence their catalogues of recordings
to radio and TV at standard rates, and they will have their own blanket
licences in place with streaming services, artist owners are more likely to
operate in a restrictive manner. The performers whose music is not available on
internet platforms such as YouTube or Spotify generally fall into two
categories. There are artists who own their copyrights and there are
artists who have the status to negotiate contractual clauses about licensing
rights with their record companies. Although in each case they are standing up
to monopolies, this does not result in music that is cheaper or more readily
available.
In addition, there are publishers who are
choosing not to be members of MCPS. They believe there is more money to be made
if they avoid the collection society’s blanket licences. Recently the BBC announced that it would no longer be able to play music by Neil Young, Bonnie
Raitt, Journey and the Doors. It was introducing a new iPlayer radio app, which
would provide users with the opportunity to listen to BBC radio offline. Wixen
music, the publisher for these artists, was not a member of MCPS and therefore
the BBC was not covered in respect of this new mechanical distribution of their
music. The publisher had decided to forego membership because they felt they
could more profitably negotiate television rights for their artists’ songs
independently. The situation was eventually resolved via an one-off agreement
between Wixen, the BBC and MCPS. The case does, however, highlight the fact
that it is not always monopolies who make music scarce or dear. On the
contrary, in modern times this fate is more likely to befall music that has
escaped the collection societies’ monopolistic demands.
No comments:
Post a Comment