Thursday, 3 September 2015

Community Chest

When campaigners have wished to curtail the duration of copyright they have called upon the public. This practice is as old as copyright law itself.
The Statute of Anne (1710) is titled ‘An Act for the Encouragement of Learning, by Vesting the Copies of Printed Books in the Authors or Purchasers of Such Copies, during the Times therein mentioned’. The time being referred to is the term of copyright, which was set at a period of 14 years and could be extended by a further 14 years if the author was still living at the end of the initial period.
The Act also indicated how it would encourage learning. Copyright would inspire writers. It would motivate ‘learned men to compose and write useful books’ because they would now have some legal assurance of getting paid. In addition, the restricted duration of copyright would boost reading, as it would lead to cheaper books. Books in copyright would be monopolistically owned: an author would have the ‘sole right’ to their books, while any bookseller to whom they assigned that right would have ‘the sole liberty of printing and reprinting such book’. Although monopolies drove up prices, the public domain would bring them down. Expiry of the term of copyright would give any bookseller the liberty to reprint the work; the ensuing competition would result in lower costs.
The price of books had been a genuine concern. Prior to the Statute of Anne, the old licensing laws had given members of the Stationers’ Company monopoly rights to book titles. When they were due for renewal in 1693, a group of peers protested about the law, stating that it ‘subjects all Learning and true Information to the arbitrary Will and Pleasure of a mercenary, and perhaps ignorant, Licenser; destroys the Properties of Authors in their Copies; and sets up many Monopolies’. The Statute of Anne aimed to curb the practice of these mercenaries, not only via limited copyright duration, but also via a clause that allowed any ‘person or persons’ to raise a complaint to the Lord Archbishop of Canterbury about any book whose price they deemed to be ‘too high and unreasonable’.
Copyright law therefore aims to achieve a balance. It has raised monopolies in order to protect the interests of authors, and it limits them in order to make their works affordable. This idea was carried through from British law into the American Constitution, which talks of promoting ‘the progress of science and useful arts, by securing for limited times to authors and inventors the exclusive right to their respective writings and discoveries’. It can also be seen in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, which counters ‘everyone has the right freely to participate in the cultural life of the community’ with ‘everyone has the right to the protection of the moral and material interests resulting from any scientific, literary or artistic production of which they are the author’. In 1841 Lord Macaulay made what is perhaps the most famous case for this balance. In a speech to the British Parliament he argued that:
Copyright is monopoly, and produces all the effects which the general voice of mankind attributes to monopoly. .... The effect of monopoly generally is to make articles scarce, to make them dear, and to make them bad. ... It is good that authors should be remunerated; and the least exceptionable way of remunerating them is by a monopoly. Yet monopoly is an evil. For the sake of the good we must submit to the evil; but the evil ought not to last a day longer than is necessary for the purpose of securing the good.
Mark Rose believes this statement is a ‘standard point of reference in discussions of the history of copyright’. It should be noted, however, that Macaulay was campaigning against an extension to copyright. It is therefore natural that the people who refer to him most are those who wish to free copyright from the extensive grip of monopolies. This includes Andrew Gowers, who quoted the speech in his 2006 Review of Intellectual Property. This report rejected an extension to sound recording copyright in Britain. Gowers argued that a properly functioning copyright system is one where ‘incentive to innovate is balanced against the ability of follow-on innovators to access knowledge’.
I think Gowers was right. If copyright is supposed to both inspire artists to create and enable audiences to access their work, extending the duration of sound recording copyright from 50 to 70 years would be of little account to either cause. I’m not sure that Macaulay was the best person to turn to, however. There is a lacuna in copyright debates. Campaigners against extension have made excellent analyses of the figure of the author, looking at the ways that corporations have hidden behind artists’ rights in order to achieve their own ends. In contrast, the effects of copyright upon the public have received less attention. Although campaigning centres upon the idea of ‘access to knowledge’, there is little investigation of how access works in different artistic fields.
Macaulay was arguing against claims for copyright extension that were being made in respect of books. Books work differently to music. Monopolies do make them expensive. Despite the textual expansion of the internet and a continuing tradition of book readings, the most common way of accessing a book is to pay for it: the majority of the trade takes place between businesses and consumers. As a result, a book that is in copyright will almost always be more costly than one that is in the public domain. In fact, in arguing that the public domain leads to cheaper prices, Gowers used the book trade as his example, even though this was in a section of the Review of Intellectual Property that was debating the merits of sound recording copyright extension. 
It should be noted, however, that there is a lot of ‘free’ music that is within copyright. Or, to put it another way, the public enjoys a lot of music without having to make a direct monetary exchange. We get to hear music for nothing on the radio; on television; in the cinema; in shopping malls; in bars, pubs and clubs; and on much of the internet, whether we are pirating or not. Many monetary transactions relating to music take place business-to-business, rather than business-to-consumer. According to PRS for Music figures from 2011 these business transactions make up nearly a third of the market for music in the UK. The value of B2B income for the music industries in that year was £1,057m, while B2C income was £2,736m (split £1,112m for recorded music and £1,624m for live music).
We do, of course, end up paying for much of this B2B music in other ways. If music is being played for free by a public broadcaster, its costs form part of the licensing fee. If it is free because it is advertising-funded, we bear the cost of that advertising in the goods we are encouraged to buy. Similarly, if music is being played for free in public premises, we pay for it indirectly via other goods that the retailers are selling us. There is also a human cost. We are denied agency: businesses choose our music for us, and they choose songs that best underpin their own needs. Moreover, we need to be aware that on many occasions when we hear music without paying for it, it is us who are being sold to advertisers.
Music’s monetary waters are muddied further when we begin to think about monopolies. There are situations when monopolies actually help to keep costs down. Most of the music that we hear over airwaves and through public address systems is paid for via blanket licences. The users of music don’t licence it directly from publishers and record companies, they instead use collection societies. In most countries there is just one collection society for each of the principal streams of income. There will be a society that collects public performance income on behalf of songwriters and publishers; a society that collects public performance income on behalf of record companies and recording artists; and a society that collects ‘mechanical’ income - money from record sales and other uses of recordings - on behalf of songwriters and publishers (the record companies act for themselves when it comes to collecting their own mechanical income and the royalties from recording sales that are due to their artists). In Britain these societies are PRS for Music, PPL and MCPS, respectively. They operate as monopolies.
One effect of blanket licensing is that all music costs the same. The BBC pays as much to play a track by the Beatles as it does to play a track by Bogshed (this is one of the reasons why it tends to use such well known music in its own promotional films). Some of the collection societies are more monopolistic than others, however. The writer members of PRS assign the performing right in their works to the society. PRS therefore ‘owns’ this right and can offer its whole repertoire of works to the broadcasters and premises it has licensing deals with. In contrast, MCPS merely administers the mechanical right. Its relationship with songwriters is instead enshrined in its Membership Agreement, which covers a number of standard and blanket licences. While PRS controls all aspects of the performing right on behalf of its members, there are some areas where MCPS members can opt out of blanket licences and instead negotiate directly with users. This includes music for films, adverts and some commercial TV broadcasters. One reason why members choose to operate in these areas is because they can negotiate higher fees. Here monopoly breaks down and the Beatles will cost more than Bogshed. PPL’s monopoly is also limited. It collects money from public premises and from broadcasters but generates little online income. The majority of this licensing is instead carried out directly by the owners of the sound recordings. PPL argue that this ‘reflects the prevailing view of record companies that downloading and on-demand streaming is analogous to the distribution of sound recordings, a traditional record company function’. Moreover, if you want to use a sound recording in an advert or a film you will have to negotiate directly with its owners. If you want to use a major star or a big hit this will cost you dearly.
As the income from recorded music declines, the money that can be made from licensing becomes more important. Consequently, some performers are seeking greater control of their rights. Artists such as Prince have successfully gained ownership of their sound recording copyrights. While most record companies use PPL to licence their catalogues of recordings to radio and TV at standard rates, and they will have their own blanket licences in place with streaming services, artist owners are more likely to operate in a restrictive manner. The performers whose music is not available on internet platforms such as YouTube or Spotify generally fall into two categories. There are artists who own their copyrights and there are artists who have the status to negotiate contractual clauses about licensing rights with their record companies. Although in each case they are standing up to monopolies, this does not result in music that is cheaper or more readily available.
In addition, there are publishers who are choosing not to be members of MCPS. They believe there is more money to be made if they avoid the collection society’s blanket licences. Recently the BBC announced that it would no longer be able to play music by Neil Young, Bonnie Raitt, Journey and the Doors. It was introducing a new iPlayer radio app, which would provide users with the opportunity to listen to BBC radio offline. Wixen music, the publisher for these artists, was not a member of MCPS and therefore the BBC was not covered in respect of this new mechanical distribution of their music. The publisher had decided to forego membership because they felt they could more profitably negotiate television rights for their artists’ songs independently. The situation was eventually resolved via an one-off agreement between Wixen, the BBC and MCPS. The case does, however, highlight the fact that it is not always monopolies who make music scarce or dear. On the contrary, in modern times this fate is more likely to befall music that has escaped the collection societies’ monopolistic demands. 

No comments:

Post a Comment